?

    <span id="8t3xa"><optgroup id="8t3xa"><center id="8t3xa"></center></optgroup></span>
        <thead id="8t3xa"><optgroup id="8t3xa"></optgroup></thead>
          |   
          Follow us

          Your ride hail driver is waiting for a raise

          Julie Zollmann Olga Morawczynski
          Platforms that claim to be marketplaces should function more like competitive markets, and less like monopolies.
          Julie Zollmann Olga Morawczynski

          Last May, just before Uber’s US$82.4 billion initial public offering, the company’s drivers together with those of rival ride-hailing platform Lyft participated in an international day of industrial action.

          They held demonstrations in 24 cities, from London to Melbourne to New York City, demanding higher pay and better working conditions.

          Grievances with ride-hailing companies that charge riders low fares and extract hefty commissions from drivers are not limited to rich economies.

          In July, driver associations in Nairobi, Kenya, urged stoppages by those working for digital-based ride-hailing services — including Uber, the Estonian company Bolt (formerly Taxify), and the locally owned Little Cab — over precisely such complaints. Although key players agreed to a set of payment principles last year, little changed in practice.

          The rise of platform labor, digitally mediated service work, creates a policy conundrum. On one hand, it benefits consumers by providing low-cost on-demand services, and can benefit workers by giving them access to those consumers. In Kenya, at least 6,000 people work as drivers for ride-hailing platforms.

          On the other hand, the quality of these new work opportunities remains unclear. While workers value the scheduling flexibility often offered by platforms, prices are set by opaque algorithms and corporate strategies. Companies are not accountable to their workers. It’s difficult to know precisely how many drivers there are, let alone what they are actually earning — though our early research in Kenya suggests there is reason to believe that it is not enough.

          When ride-hailing companies first emerged, they attracted drivers with high fares. But, in an effort to increase ridership, they slashed prices over time. Because the additional rides were insufficient to offset the drop in per-mile rates, drivers’ hourly earnings plummeted.

          This practice was apparent everywhere, but it was particularly painful for drivers in low-income markets, where, unlike in the United States or Canada, they typically acquire a vehicle specifically for the job, using their savings or taking out loans. They may also lease vehicles from car owners, called “partners,” on fixed weekly terms.

          As their earnings fell, drivers struggled to cover their fixed costs. Forced to work longer hours, some ended up in fatigue-related accidents, according to both drivers and local insurers. In response, Uber imposed new limits on drivers — they could work for no more than 12 hours at a time, with at least a six-hour break in between.

          For many drivers in Kenya, simply leaving the industry is not an option, owing to outstanding debts, depreciation of productive assets, and a lack of alternative income-generating options in a country where only 16 per cent of workers have formal jobs.

          Desperate to make ends meet, many have been forced to maximize work hours by using multiple apps. Our early research in Kenya suggests that a typical driver in Kenya works 12-hour days, six days per week.

          Still, not all drivers support the strikes. Some, particularly those who purchased their own cars or have some offline clients, are relatively satisfied with the platforms.

          Effective regulations are needed

          While they would prefer fairer rate-setting practices, they say the frequent strikes are not worth the lost revenue. These drivers report feeling pessimistic that government will intervene on their behalf. Some drivers we interviewed believe that driver-association leaders organize strikes for self-serving reasons. But choosing not to participate in a strike carries significant risks.

          During the May strikes, participants used WhatsApp to divide themselves into groups, with each covering a geographic zone. Their job was to intercept drivers who, in their view, were undermining the cause. Sometimes, they damaged the spoilers’ vehicles or confiscated their mobile phones.

          As Benson, an early entrant into the online taxi business, told us: “Most drivers don’t work during strikes for their own safety and that of their cars, not because they are also striking.”

          There is only one way to ensure that ride-hailing platforms deliver for both riders and drivers — better government regulation. To this end, governments must first clarify who has the relevant regulatory authority.

          In Kenya, drivers are given permits by the National Transport Safety Administration. But platforms like Uber, which are registered as technology firms, are not under the NTSA’s jurisdiction.

          The Cabinet Secretary for Labor and Director General of the Competition Authority of Kenya also stated that intervening in platform pay was out of their remits. This leaves drivers with nowhere to turn, and puts platforms at risk of future radical state intervention.

          Once a regulatory authority is designated, it will need to design effective policies, which requires data. As it stands, platforms not only control pricing, but also hold troves of rider and driver data, creating significant information asymmetries between platforms and drivers, and between platforms and policymakers. Regulators should insist on access to the information they need to make sound policy judgments.

          Platforms that claim to be marketplaces should function more like competitive markets, and less like monopolies. Strikes can draw attention to the problem. But only well-crafted regulations can fix it.

          Julie Zollmann is a PhD candidate at The Fletcher School at Tufts University. Olga Morawczynski is Senior Program Manager at the Mastercard Foundation. Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2019.

          www.project-syndicate.org

          ?
          Special Reports
          ?
          ?
               
          主站蜘蛛池模板: 免费人成大片在线观看播放| 老司机亚洲精品影院在线观看| 九九热久久免费视频| 亚洲AV日韩精品一区二区三区 | EEUSS影院WWW在线观看免费| 免费A级毛片无码A∨男男| 国产午夜亚洲精品不卡| 亚洲AV中文无码乱人伦在线视色| 国产亚洲精彩视频| 国产亚洲午夜高清国产拍精品 | 在线亚洲97se亚洲综合在线 | 四虎免费影院ww4164h| 亚洲嫩草影院在线观看| 国产成人午夜精品免费视频| 亚洲国产精品日韩av不卡在线| 国产午夜鲁丝片AV无码免费| 一级黄色免费网站| 亚洲AV午夜成人片| 日本亚洲免费无线码| 亚洲AV成人无码网站| 亚洲一级Av无码毛片久久精品| 久久最新免费视频| 亚洲欧洲国产成人精品| 日美韩电影免费看| 成人无码精品1区2区3区免费看| 亚洲视频在线一区| 成人免费看吃奶视频网站| 日韩毛片在线免费观看| 亚洲精品V欧洲精品V日韩精品 | 可以免费观看的毛片| 亚洲乱码卡三乱码新区| 国产亚洲福利一区二区免费看| 国产黄片不卡免费| 亚洲中文字幕久久精品无码2021| 日韩一级视频免费观看| 18禁超污无遮挡无码免费网站| 亚洲最大av资源站无码av网址| 亚洲性日韩精品一区二区三区| 国产一卡2卡3卡4卡无卡免费视频| 国产精品亚洲五月天高清| 99久久精品国产亚洲|